Entrepreneurship
and Work in a Post-Fordist Organization: the Case of an
Italian Industrial District
1. Different patterns of
organization
In order to introduce you to the
transformation of work and participation that has taken
place in the North East of Italy, I think its best
to start with a simple diagram. This describes the
footwear production process (picture 1 - Patterns of
development in footwear production).
In Italy three different
kinds of organization may be found within a single
technical process (in this case, footwear).
Each of the three production
methods shown in the diagram produces the same
product (or family of products), has the same technology,
the same number of employees with identical skills, the
same output at the end of the process (and also at any
single stage of the process) and the same standard of
productivity, cost and wage distribution.
The most important
difference concerns the social agreement: the degree of
participation in capital investment and income
distribution.
In the first pattern (the
integrated firm or fordist organization), market
analysis, decision making, profit and capital investment
are highly concentrated in one head office at the top of
the value chain. Workers and bosses just attend to the
top managers decisions and behave in relation to a
contract formally sanctioning a low level of
participation further down the chain in those stages of
the process that are far from the final market line.
In the third pattern,
though, (the industrial district or post-fordist
organization) market analysis, product design, decision
making, profit and investment are shared among a wide
number of entrepreneurs.
In the other pattern of
organization (the network enterprise) all these functions
are performed by quasi-entrepreneurs (exclusive
sub-contractors for one head enterprise), in a mixture of
market and hierarchy (in this case participation of
sub-contractors in the general strategy of the chain is
limited to technical choices).
In the last decade the non-fordist
mode of production has become predominant in North East
Italy mainly for two reasons:
- it is suited to
globalization, more flexible in the face of market
failure, and able to promote a team game among
entrepreneurs and workers at different levels, ensuring
quicker innovation along the line, reducing risks, time
to market and the cost of re-shaping the system in the
event of external shocks;
- large amounts of capital
are not required for each participant in the value chain
to follow a successful path of development.
2. Why have post-fordist
modes of production taken the leadership in Italy ?
The first organization
seems rigid in the face of external shocks and unable, in
Italy, to shift toward lean production or any other kind
of risk-sharing social agreement.
In this mode of production
a market failure affects the structure as a whole, with
high costs in re-allocating human resources and capital
goods. If the top manager fails in market forecasts and
loses part of his market share to other competitors, the
company as a whole goes bankrupt and employees and
machinery have to be transferred elsewhere, with high
economic and social costs.
On the contrary, the
network enterprise and the industrial district have a
capacity to absorb external shocks without evident costs.
If the failure is the result of a mistake committed by
the top manager of one of the district head enterprises,
the only consequence to industrial suppliers (independent
sub-contractors in this case) is their need to change the
destination of their output. The industrial section of
the chain is not affected by external shocks and its
members are simply forced to shift from the failing head
enterprise to another, quickly joining the winning team.
A fordist organization,
however, can be established only with the help of big
banks or by wealthy families. The total amount of capital
needed to develop a new integrated company is high, while
total profit is concentrated in very few hands.
In the post-fordist
organization, on the other hand, each entrepreneur has to
invest only what is required at his own stage of the
process: it is easier for him to find the money, or a
bank to provide a small loan. Meanwhile the total profits
are shared among a large number of stock and stake
holders.
Italy is a country
typified by small banks and family capital. A
post-fordist organization (in which risk, investment and
profit are shared among a lot of people) is more than an
opportunity, it is a compulsory course of development.
3. The rising of a new
kind of entrepreneurship and work
We here briefly describe
the rise of a new participative game in Italy: small
entrepreneurs and skilled workers continuously shifting
from one chain to another, from one job to another,
concerned only with joining the winning team.
Of course this is possible
only in a local context (the atmosphere of a district)
that allows anyone to shift without dramatic changes in
habits, friends, home, culture, etc., and this is
possible only where the territory plays the special role
of a good social integrator.
The local district, a term
identifying the territory where a community of people and
a population of small firms join together (see F.Pyke,
W.Sengenberger, F.Cossentino or G.Becattini by
ILO-Geneva, 1991 and 1997, or P.Krugmans "Geography
and Trade", 1991), is the environment in which a
new kind of entrepreneurship and work can take off.
A small businessmen is,
first of all, a member of the community and part of a
team (not of a social class). He knows that his success
depends on cooperation more than on competition, and for
this reason he participates in local institutions and
associations.
Workers also feel they
belong to a system, not to a single company. They look at
their own career as being the first step in a possible
entrepreneurial upgrading process that starts with
sub-contracting and carries on to head enterprise.
When we say workers in
North East Italy we mean skilled workers. Skilled
(and affluent) workers are a large part of the
work force because of the prevalence of traditional
sectors and the technical structure of the process which
is still oriented towards custom-made products and a high
level of customer service.
In this context, learning
by doing is the standard way of improving human
resources. But the ability to bargain individual
know-how within the factory and in the territory is
also an important part of the learning process.
4. What, then, is
participation in these organizations we refer to as post-fordist
(non-fordist) organizations ?
Although entrepreneurs
believe in free market laws, individual interest and so
on, and though they represent a single stage of the
process (as sub-contractors), they naturally tend to
cooperate in the final success of the chain.
In order to survive (as
entrepreneurs) they are forced to understand, anticipate
and influence the strategy of head companies; they must
participate in the collective shift of the district
towards a new challenge and use competition and
cooperation as non-alternative means of growth.
Participation in this case
is compulsory: an entrepreneur must take part in the
collective game of the district or he may be pushed out
and suffer social downgrading.
Up-grading and downgrading
have no apparent consequences on the economic condition
of people living in a district (there are no startling
income differences between a small owner with 5 to 10
workers, a single handed entrepreneur and a
skilled worker), but being identified as a loser
may have dramatic consequences (emigration).
Workers, on the other
hand, have a special opportunity on the district labor
market: in a territory with hundreds of firms performing
similar tasks, using similar machinery and techniques,
and continually searching for new ideas and skills, they
can choose their company.
The local labor market in
a district is a perfect labor market (at least for
skilled workers, but also offering good chances to
others).
In this case participation
comes from the awareness that a worker can control part
of the output and measure the improvement of his own
professional skills. Every day a worker can measure the
value of his own personal capital, and participate in the
design of new products and the re-shaping of the work
process.
These special conditions
are currently attracting worldwide interest in the
Italian pattern of development and its economic and
social success. They may represent the rise of a new
pattern of development or what someone has recently
called "The End of Work" (Rifkin).
Paolo Gurisatti
|